CAPITALISM AND THE CORPORATE
STATE
[El
fascismo de ayer y de hoy: los mismos financistas, los mismos métodos]
Excerpts from George Seldes’s 1935 book about Mussolini, Sawdust Caesar:
Annexed to the
article: What’s Obama
Up to, with His TPP & TTIP?. Posted on April 26, 2015 by Eric Zuesse. http://www.washingtonsblog.com/
. April 26, 15.
by Benito Mussolini, November, 1933
Is this crisis which
has afflicted us for four years a crisis in the system or of the system?
This is a serious question. I answer: The crisis has so deeply penetrated
the system that it has become a crisis of the system. It is no longer an
ailment; it is a constitutional disease.
Today we are able to
say that the method of capitalistic production is vanquished, and with it
the theory of economic liberalism which has illustrated and excused it. I
want to outline in a general way the history of capitalism in the last
century, which may be called the capitalistic century. But first of all,
what is capitalism?
Capitalism is … a method
of industrial production. To employ the most comprehensive definition:
Capitalism is a method of mass production for mass consumption, financed
en masse by the emission of private, national and international capital.
Capitalism is therefore industrial and has not had in the field of
agriculture any manifestation of great bearing.
I would mark in the
history of capitalism three periods: the dynamic period, the static period, and
the period of decline.
The dynamic period
was that from 1830 to 1870. It coincided with the introduction of weaving
by machinery and with the appearance of the locomotive. Manufacturing, the
typical manifestation of industrial capitalism, expanded. This was the epoch of
great expansion and hence of the law of free competition; the struggle of
all against all had full play.
In this period there
were crises, but they were cyclical crises, neither long nor universal.
Capitalism still had such vitality and such power of recovery that it
could brilliantly prevail.
There were also wars.
They cannot be compared with the World War. They were brief. Even the War
of 1870, with its tragic days at Sedan, took no more than a couple of
seasons.
During the forty
years of the dynamic period the State was watching; it was remote, and the
theorists of liberalism could say: ‘You, the State, have a single duty. It
is to see to it that your administration does not in the least turn toward the
economic sector. The better you govern the less you will occupy yourself
with the problems of the economic realm.’ We find, therefore, that economy
in all its forms was limited only by the penal and commercial codes.
But after 1870, this
epoch underwent a change. There was no longer the struggle for life, free
competition, the selection of the strongest. There became manifest the
first symptoms of the fatigue and the devolution of the capitalistic
method. There began to be agreements, syndicates, corporations, trusts.
One may say that there was not a sector of economic life in the countries
of Europe and America where these forces which characterize capitalism did
not appear.
What was the result?
The end of free competition. Restricted as to its borders, capitalistic
enterprise found that, rather than fight, it was better to concede, to
ally, to unite by dividing the markets and sharing the profits. The very
law of demand and supply was now no longer a dogma, because through the
combines and the trusts it was possible to control demand and
supply.
Finally, this
capitalistic economy, unified,’trustified,’ turned toward the State. What
inspired it to do so? Tariff protection.
Liberalism, which is
nothing but a wider form of the doctrine of economic liberalism, received
a death blow. The nation which, from the first, raised almost
insurmountable trade barriers was the United States, but today even
England has renounced all that seemed traditional in her political, economic
and moral life, and has surrendered herself to a constantly increasing
protectionism.
After the World War,
and because of it, capitalistic enterprise became inflated. Enterprises grew in
size from millions to billions. Seen from a distance, this vertical sweep
of things appeared as something monstrous, babel-like. Once, the spirit
had dominated the material; now it was the material which bent and joined
the spirit. Whatever had been physiological was now pathological; all
became abnormal.
At this stage,
super-capitalism draws its inspiration and its justification from this Utopian
theory: the theory of unlimited consumers. The ideal of super-capitalism
would be the standardization of the human race from the cradle to the
coffin. Super-capitalism would have all men born of the same length, so
that all cradles could be standardized; it would have babies divert themselves
with the same playthings, men clothed according to the same pattern, all
reading the same book and having the same taste for the movies — in other
words, it would have everybody desiring a single utilitarian machine. This
is in the logic of things, because only in this way can super-capitalism
do what it wishes.
When does
capitalistic enterprise cease to be an economic factor? When its size
compels it to be a social factor. And that, precisely, is the moment when
capitalistic enterprise, finding itself in difficulty, throws itself into
the very arms of the State; It is the moment when the intervention of the
State begins, rendering itself ever more necessary.
We are at this point:
that, if in all the nations of Europe the State were to go to sleep for
twenty-four hours, such an interval would be sufficient to cause a
disaster. Now, there is no economic field in which the State is not called
upon to intervene. Were we to surrender — just as a matter of hypothesis —
to this capitalism of the eleventh hour, we should arrive at State
capitalism, which is nothing but State socialism inverted.
This is the crisis of
the capitalist system, taken in its universal significance. …
Last evening I
presented an order in which I defined the new corporation system as we
understand it and wish to make it.
I should like to fix
your attention on what was called the object: the well-being of the
Italian people. It is necessary that, at a certain time, these
institutions, which we have created, be judged and measured directly by the
masses as instruments through which these masses may improve their
standard of living. Some day the worker, the tiller of the soil, will say
to himself and to others: ‘If today I am better off practically, I owe it
to the institutions which the Fascist revolution has created.’
We want the Italian
workers, those who are interested in their status as Italians, as workers,
as Fascists, to feel that we have not created institutions solely to give
form to our doctrinal schemes, but in order, at a certain moment, to give
positive, concrete, practical and tangible results.
Our State is not an
absolute State. Still less is it an absolutory State, remote from men and
armed only with inflexible laws, as laws ought to be. Our State is one
organic, human State which wishes to adhere to the realities of life.
…
Today we bury
economic liberalism. The corporation plays on the economic terrain just as
the Grand Council and the militia play on the political terrain.
Corporationism is disciplined economy, and from that comes control,
because one cannot imagine a discipline without a director.
Corporationism is
above socialism and above liberalism. A new synthesis is created. It is a
symptomatic fact that the decadence of capitalism coincides with the
decadence of socialism. All the Socialist parties of Europe are in
fragments.
Evidently the two
phenomena — I will not say conditions — present a point of view which is
strictly logical: there is between them a historical parallel. Corporative
economy arises at the historic moment when both the militant phenomena,
capitalism and socialism, have already given all that they could give. From one
and from the other we inherit what they have of vitality.
We have rejected the
theory of the economic man, the Liberal theory, and we are, at the same
time, emancipated from what we have heard said about work being a
business. The economic man does not exist; the integral man, who is
political, who is economic, who is religious, who is holy, who is
combative, does exist.
Today we take again a
decisive step on the road of the revolution.
Let us ask a final
question: Can corporationism be applied to other countries? We are obliged
to ask this question because it will be asked in all countries where
people are studying and trying to understand us. There is no doubt that,
given the general crisis of capitalism, corporative solutions can be
applied anywhere. But in order to make corporationism full and complete,
integral, revolutionary, certain conditions are required.
There must be a
single party through which, aside from economic discipline, enters into
action also political discipline, which shall serve as a chain to bind the
opposing factions together, and a common faith.
But this is not
enough. There must be the supremacy of the State, so that the State may
absorb, transform and embody all the energy, all the interests, all the
hopes of a people.
Still, not enough.
The third and last and the most important condition is that there must be lived
a period of the highest ideal tension.
We are now living in
this period of high, ideal tension. It is because step by step we give force
and consistency to all our acts; we translate in part all our doctrine.
How can we deny that this, our Fascista, is a period of exalted, ideal
tension?
No one can deny it.
This is the time in which arms are crowned with victory. Institutions are
remade, the land is redeemed, cities are founded.
====
No hay comentarios:
Publicar un comentario